Presented at the WHO/WTO Joint Secretariat Workshop on Differential Pricing and Financing of Essential Drugs.
April 11, 2001
Hosbjor, Norway
James Love
Director
Consumer Project on Technology
http://www.cptech.org
Problems with the IPR system
Aggressive Patenting May Stifle Gene Discovery BenefitsLOS ANGELES TIMES -- WASHINGTON
In one of the landmark cases dealing with the controversy involving human gene patenting, researchers at the University of Pennsylvania argue that patent holder Myriad Genetics, a Utah company, used its ownership claims on two genes to stifle development of new tests and treatments for breast cancer.
Early work on the genes, called BRCA1 and BRCA2, followed what used to be a familiar pattern. Scientists at several institutions raced to locate and decode the genes, which are linked to families with high rates of breast and ovarian cancers. Myriad, collaborating with the National Institutes of Health, got to BRCA1 first and later claimed it was first to BRCA2 as well.
Researchers, including Pennsylvania University's lab research director Arupa Ganguly, followed up by developing tests for variations in the genes that can signal susceptibility to disease. By 1998, the Penn lab was performing more than 700 tests a year.
That's when Myriad used its patent to pull the plug. It notified Ganguly and her colleagues that they could no longer do more than a handful of tests. The company also required the genes' co- discoverer, former NIH collaborator Phillip Futreal, to pay Myriad for tests he needed for his research. And it set a $2,580 fee for the test, more than twice that charged by most other labs, including Penn's.
Recently, after a furor over the fee, the company relented and agreed to charge only $1,200 when federally funded research such as Futreal's is involved.
In the twenty-five months transpiring between the filing of the initial complaint in this consolidated patent infringement action on May 14, 1991, and the commencement of the trial on June 28, 1993, approximately five hundred forty-one pleadings have been filed and dozens of hearings on motions and discovery matters have been conducted by the court. The court has entered eighty- eight written orders and numerous bench rulings. Thus, the court is intimately familiar with the facts of this case and the legal contentions of the parties. To state that the case has been hotly contested would be an understatement. The parties have amassed learned, experienced and sizable trial teams who have represented their clients zealously and competently. The administrative complexity [of] conducting a trial of this magnitude has been enormous for the court and the parties. The sixty-year- old courtroom in New Bern, North Carolina, has been converted into a contemporary high tech facility utilizing real time court reporting and six computer-integrated video display monitors. It is highly conceivable that the cost of this trial for the parties exceeds $100,000 per day, in addition to the time and expense associated with this court and the jury. As the case enters its fourth week of trial, the parties estimate, somewhat conservatively the court suspects, that the trial will last an additional six to eight weeks.
First of all, frequency of litigation and the cost of litigation for biotech patents is very high. Drug and health patents are litigated more than any other kind of technology. There is one empirical study that showed that six lawsuits are spawned by every 100 corporate biotech patents. There is also research that shows that most of the start-up companies are spending a comparable amount on legal costs to what they are spending on research. So this is a very big concern for start-up companies.
Considerations concerning parallel trade
Production for Export
Global convention on R&D
The WTO paper discusses price discrimination for drugs in terms of Ramsey pricing, and others have addressed this. Ramsey is a term used first to describe issues in public utility regulation, where there were big fixed costs and low marginal costs, and hence increasing returns to scale, and departures from marginal cost were necessary to recoup the fixed costs. Since marginal cost pricing would not meet the budget constraint of the enterprise, Ramsey and others (before him) examined the issue of how best to price the good or service. In particular, he focused on classic notions of economic efficiency, as measured by consumer surplus, and like most such analysis, ignoring distributional issues.
Ramsey's insight (he was not the first it turns out), was that pricing similar to a monopolist was economically efficient, if both could engage in price discrimination. The less elastic the demand for the good (the higher the willingness to pay), the less consumer (social) surplus that was lost. The Ramsey solution was not the monopolist solution, however, because Ramsey limited the increases over marginal cost to only that necessary to pay for the fixed costs. Ramsey would price according to what the market would bear, but only up to a point when the enterprise met its budget constraint. The Ramsey solution is often used to some degree by regulators, but with some limitations, because it has some problems.
One illustration of this is from the optimal tax theory, where it was quickly shown that a ramsey solution would involve shifting taxes away from many luxury goods, and more problematic, to things like life saving medicines. For example, under ramsey pricing, one would have *very* high taxes on insulin, and use this revenue to say pay for roads. Any medicine that treated a severe illness was a target for a Ramsey tax. The demand was "inelastic" because people really needed it. Not very many people thought this was a great way to design taxes. It turns out people do care about distributional issues.
Monopolies of one sort or another were fascinated with Ramsey pricing, because it provides a nice rationale for behavior that looked a lot like what a monopolist wanted to do. Thus, for example, in the early 80s the railroads claimed that deregulation of "captive" shippers of coal and grain, was "Ramsey efficient," because they were recouping fixed costs from those who had no alternatives, and hence, were relatively price inelastic. The railroads even got Ken Arrow to sign a letter on this. Price gouging (whoops, I mean Ramsey efficient pricing) of captive airline markets also leads to similar claims that this is just an efficiency justified pricing scheme (not a true statement, of course).
The big problem with Ramsey pricing is that everyone loves to push the price discrimination part, which is pricing according to what people are willing to pay, but there is considerably less enthusiasm for the other part, which is the budget constraint. And, without the government regulation of the budget constraint, you just have monopoly pricing, which is not in fact efficient, in most cases, not to mention the ethical issues, or the rather messy empirical realities of industry pricing practices.
So it is somewhat ironic that at the center of a debate over how to help the poor, we are showcasing theories of why letting big pharma engage in monopoly like price discrimination, without any price controls, is the answer.
1. 26 AIPLA Quarterly Journal 185 (1998)
2. Burroughs Wellcome Co. v. Barr Lab., 828 F. Supp. 1208,
1209 (E.D.N.C. 1993).
3.
http://www.bu.edu/law/scitech/volume6/Panel2.htm. The
text referred to studies by Josh Lerner, The Importance of
Trade Secrecy: Evidence from Civil Litigation, paper
presented to the Conference on the Economics of Intellectual
Property Rights, ICARE Institute, University of Venice,
Italy (October 6-8, 1994), and Jean O. Lanjouw & Mark
Schankerman, Stylized Facts Of Patent Litigation: Value,
Scope And Ownership 3 (National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 6297, 1997) (noting that crowded fields
and new fields of technology generate more patent
litigation); Jean O. Lanjouw & Josh Lerner, The Enforcement
Of Intellectual Property Rights: A Survey Of The Empirical
Literature 13 (National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper No. 6292, 1997) (correlating number of times that a
patent is cited in future applications to the value of the
patent and noting that innovative technology patents are
cited with increased frequency).
4. The US legislation on "reimportation" of pharmaceutical
drugs, a limited and so far unused provision authorizing
parallel imports, did not change US patent law.
Tables