Compulsory Licensing: Models For State Practice In Developing Countries, Access
to Medicine and Compliance with the WTO TRIPS Accord:
Prepared for the United Nations Development Programme
January 21, 2001
James Love
Consumer Project on Technology
http://www.cptech.org
-
Introduction.1
-
This note addresses the issue of government authorization to
use a patent without the permission of the patent owner. In
particular, models for compulsory licensing and government use of
patents are examined, as a tool to increase access to medicines
in developing countries. 2 The recommendations in this paper are
informed by the following facts.
- Contrary to much of the debate over the World Trade
Organization rules for intellectual property, the TRIPS accord is
actually fairly permissive in terms of what is permitted in terms
of government decisions to authorize third parties to use patents
without the permission of the patent owners. For example, for
public non-commercial use, a country may use or authorize a third
party to use a patent without negotiation or without a license
(31.b), the only obligation being the payment of "adequate"
compensation (31.h). This approach too can be used for
emergencies, including public health emergencies (31.b). When
an authorization is to remedy anticompetitive practices, such as
high prices from the exercise of monopoly power, the products can
even be exported (31.k). The TRIPS also allows countries to
make virtually all of its decisions on these issues, including
those regarding compensation or appeals, through administrative
processes (31.c, 31.i, 31.j, 31.k). Moreover, the TRIPS
specifically does not require governments to grant injunctive
relief to patent holders (44.2) in cases where government
authorizations of patent use satisfy the Article 31 framework.
Taken together, these provisions in the existing TRIPS accord
permit countries to create very simple and easy to administer
systems for permitting production or import of generic products
from the competitive sector. However, what the TRIPS permits and
what countries actually do are two different things, and in the
end, it is national law and practice that will be decisive, both
in terms of providing access to inventions, including medicines,
and in establishing the state practice framework in which TRIPS
rules will be interpreted. Also, there remains an important
issue with respect to the degree to which countries can tailor
their laws to specific concerns regarding access to medicines,
due to the Article 27.1 restrictions on discrimination of patent
rights by field of technology.
-
Many governments have good national laws for public use of
patents, which is a similar but more direct and less restrictive
method of authorizing non-voluntary use of a patent than a
compulsory license. For example, under 28 USC Sec 1498, the US
government can use patents or authorize third parties to use
patents for virtually any public use, without negotiation.
Patent owners have no rights for injunctive relief, and may only
seek compensation, not as a tort, but as an eminent domain
taking.3 This is not unique, however, and the Australian, Irish,
Italian, German, New Zealand and UK public use provisions also
provide very similar powers, as do several other countries,
including the Philippines, Malaysian and Singapore, among others.
See below for example of specific national laws on this. The
TRIPS rules are designed to accommodate these practices.
- Compulsory licenses have been used extensively in North
America, Japan, and Europe for a variety of purposes, including
many that have been issued for computers, software, biotechnology
and other modern technologies. In 2000 the US issued several
compulsory licenses for tow truck technologies. Canada has the
most extensive experience with the use of compulsory licenses for
pharmaceutical drugs. Until pressured by the US, as a condition
to join NAFTA, to abandon a compulsory licensing approach that
was nearly automatic, Canada routinely granted compulsory
licenses on pharmaceuticals, with compensation based upon
royalties, typically set at 4 percent of the competitor's sales
price.
- Despite a public health crisis of enormous proportions for
HIV/AIDS, apparently no African country has issued a compulsory
license for any medicine. Given the permissive global trade
framework for compulsory licensing, one has to wonder why this is
so.
- Virtually all national patent law systems are modeled after
European and US patent legal traditions, often based upon
colonial statutes, or the modern day equivalent, laws informed by
WIPO technical assistance.
- The United States spends $1 billion annually on its patent
and trademark office. Europe and Japan also spend large sums to
examine patents. Despite these investments in rich countries,
the quality of US patent examinations is poor. According to a
study by Lemley and Allison of patents litigated to judgment, 54%
were found to be valid, and 46% were invalid.4 Critics of US
patent examinations believe a much larger number of issued
patents are not valid under any reasonable tests of utility and
invention, and would be busted if the patent owners sought
enforcement. Patent examinations in developing countries, if
they exist at all, are under staffed, under trained and have less
access to research materials on prior art.5
- The costs of litigation are not trivial. In (December 27)
1998, the New York Times reported the median cost of US patent
litigation was $1.2 million, per side, and the costs of
litigation in complex cases is much higher. In Polaroid v.
Kodak, each side reportedly spent over $100 million. Consider
this quote from a Judge in the AZT patent dispute.6
In the twenty-five months transpiring between
the filing of the initial complaint in this
consolidated patent infringement action on
May 14, 1991, and the commencement of the
trial on June 28, 1993, approximately five
hundred forty-one pleadings have been filed
and dozens of hearings on motions and
discovery matters have been conducted by the
court. The court has entered eighty-eight
written orders and numerous bench rulings.
Thus, the court is intimately familiar with
the facts of this case and the legal
contentions of the parties.
To state that the case has been hotly
contested would be an understatement. The
parties have amassed learned, experienced and
sizable trial teams who have represented
their clients zealously and competently.
The administrative complexity [of] conducting
a trial of this magnitude has been enormous
for the court and the parties. The sixty-year-
old courtroom in New Bern, North Carolina,
has been converted into a contemporary high
tech facility utilizing real time court
reporting and six computer-integrated video
display monitors. It is highly conceivable
that the cost of this trial for the parties
exceeds $100,000 per day, in addition to the
time and expense associated with this court
and the jury. As the case enters its fourth
week of trial, the parties estimate, somewhat
conservatively the court suspects, that the
trial will last an additional six to eight
weeks.
See also this quote by Professor Michael Meurer:7
First of all, frequency of litigation and the
cost of litigation for biotech patents is
very high. Drug and health patents are
litigated more than any other kind of
technology. There is one empirical study
that showed that six lawsuits are spawned by
every 100 corporate biotech patents.[17]8
There is also research that shows that most
of the start-up companies are spending a
comparable amount on legal costs to what they
are spending on research.[18]9 So this is a
very big concern for start-up companies.
- Few if any developing countries have a significant capacity
to examine patent applications, or to litigate patent claims.
Some developing countries have patent registration systems that
don't require patent examination at all. In the US, Japan or
European market, there are substantial financial incentives for
generic drug companies to bust bad patents. These incentives do
not exist in small national markets. It is predictable that a
considerable number of patents in developing countries will be
bad patents, because the countries or competitors will not have
the capacity or economic incentives to evaluate and litigate
overreaching patent claims.
- For a variety of reasons, poor countries are extremely
reluctant to sue or be sued. Litigation is expensive, and can
overwhelm already limited program budgets. In some countries, a
cultural reluctance to engage in litigation restrains public
officials from pursuing courses of action likely to involve
protracted litigation.
- Developing countries have not enacted good TRIPS compliant
state practice models for authorizing the use of patents on
medicines. Prior to the TRIPS, many countries simply excluded
pharmaceutical from the patent system. Under TRIPS, countries
must issue patents on medicines. Unless they can invent a model
for state practice that will actually work in developing
countries, countries will not be able to obtain less expensive
medicines from the competitive sector.
-
Summary of Good State Practice.
- This memo outlines a model for government authorizations of
uses of patents without the permission of the patent owner. In
particular, this is designed to address cases where the country
or generic entrants do not maintain the capacity to invest
significant resources in litigation. While I am interested in
the development of a state practice model for a developing
country, I have also drawn on examples from patent laws in
developed countries. People looking at these issues can obtain
translations of foreign IPR laws from WIPO in both paper and
electronic formats. CPT has excerpted sections of several patent
laws, including compulsory licensing, government use and patent
exception provisions, for a web page here:
http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/cl/examples2.html.
- The recommended features for a good state practice model are
as follows:
One. The system must not be overly legalistic or expensive
to administer, or easily manipulated by litigation. The large
pharmaceutical companies are masters of IPR litigation and
routinely misuse regulatory and IPR laws, exploit loopholes, and
harass competitors, in the courts. Any system which permits the
big Pharma companies to do this will not work very well in
practice. For this reason, we recommend models that rely upon
administrative processes.
Two. The government use provisions should be strong. The
rules in the TRIPS give governments very broad powers to
authorize use of patents for public non-commercial use, and this
is one area where there are many good state practice models to
consider. No developing country should have statutory public use
provisions that are weaker than the US, German, Irish, or UK
provisions.
Three. The system of setting compensation should be
relatively predictable and easy to administer. We recommend
adoption of royalty guidelines, to reduce uncertainly, and to
speed decisions, and an administrative process that places
burdens on patent owners to disclose essential economics data if
they seek to appeal administrative decisions. It is important to
have greater transparency in this area. This process should also
be fast, with initial decisions setting initial compensation, and
revisions, such as from administrative appeals, providing forward
looking adjustments. When there are complex IP rights for a
product, as is sometimes the case for medical technologies, one
approach is to permit a decision setting a royalty for all claims
to be paid into an escrow fund, and to have the various patent
owners settle claims between each other, possibly through
arbitration, with the arbitration costs borne by the competing
patent owners.
Four. Production for export should be permitted. Under
the TRIPS, the most straightforward way would be to permit
exports if (a) the administrative process found that a lack of
competition within the therapeutic class of drugs has given the
producer market power, creating a barrier to access. This would
be consistent with Article 31.k of the TRIPS. This can be done
by a Health agency, even by administrative action. A different
approach would be to authorize production for export when the
legitimate interests of the patent owner are protected in the
export market, such as when the export market provides reasonable
compensation to the patent owner, as an Article 30 exception to
patent rights. A number of NGOs are also urging countries to
adopt an Article 30 patent exception for products that are
produced for humanitarian purposes. The Article 31.k and Article
30 approach are both stronger if accompanied with an
administrative finding, such as finding that (a) increasing
returns to scale in the production of a product are important,
(b) the product is used to treat infectious diseases, (c) the
export of the product will benefit the public health, and/or (d)
the export of the product will address humanitarian objectives.
Five. There should be a provision for authorization of the
use of patents to address public health emergencies. Under 31.b,
this triggers the same fast track liberal procedures as exist for
public non-commercial use. Many European governments have a
large public sector role in funding health care, but for most
developing countries, there is little capacity to provide
expensive drugs for HIV/AIDs or other severe illnesses. In these
countries, it is possible to expand access to now expensive drugs
by permitting the competitive generics sector to enter the
commercial market, where the are opportunities for expanded
access to medicines, at least among some income groups. By
declaring a public health emergency for HIV/AIDs, tuberculosis,
malaria or other illnesses, a government could give general
authorization for the competitive sector to supply particular
types of drugs, subject to paying a modest royalty to the patent
owner, and can eliminate the steps of negotiation normally
required for commercial use, saving time and lowering barriers to
entry, and probably increasing the number of generic competitors.
In our opinion, this should be done right now for all HIV/AIDS
related medicines in Africa, Romania, Thailand and other
countries where AIDS drugs are protected by patent, and the high
price creates access barriers.
Administrative processes.
- As indicated above, the TRIPS permits the use of
administrative practices in all Article 31 decisions, including
the setting of compensation and the appeals processes. The key
thing for each country is to settle basic issues. Determine
which agency, official, committee or other body will make the
initial decision, and which will receive and act on appeals. The
TRIPS requires that the processes be fair, transparent, and
accountable, relying, for example, on written records and
decisions, with opportunities to provide evidence and be heard,
and that there exist an appeals process by an independent body
from the one that makes the initial decision.
- Several countries give very broad powers to a wide range of
government officials to make decisions regarding the initial
authorization of use, when the use involves public non-commercial
use. In some cases, including the US, the statute gives the
power to authorize the use of the patent to any government
official, for example by issuing a contract or agreement that
contains the authorization to use patents or copyrights, and the
agency's administrative procedures may provide additional
guidance on how these decisions are made, such as, for example,
the procedures spelled out in the US federal acquisition
regulations.
- The procedures for authorizing third parties to engage in
commercial use of a patent tend to more specific, in terms of who
can make such an authorization. In Belgium, the statute
provides for a committee that includes persons representing
consumer, labor and small business interests. In Switzerland,
compulsory licensing decisions are made by the Federal Council.
In many countries, the licenses are issued by the registrar of
patents or the ministries of trade or industry. In the US, the
Secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services makes
the determination in cases involving the Bayh-Dole "March-In"
rights, while compulsory licensing of patents for nuclear energy
or clean air are handled by different bodies. In Spain, the
Minister of Industry is required to consult with the Minister of
Health on compulsory licensing applications that involve patents
that concern the public health.
- Article 31 of the TRIPS requires that the administrative
process provide an "independent review by a distinct higher
authority." For example, the Minister of Health could appoint an
officer to make decisions, and also an independent body to review
decisions, with the power to overrule, modify or remand the
initial decisions. The review could be provided by another
office, such as the registrar of patents, the Attorney General.
The task is to create a system that will carry out the purposes
of the compulsory licensing or government use program, and to
have a process that is and is perceived to be fair and
straightforward. With respect to Article 31, the TRIPS is more
about having a rules based system than it is about the specific
rule or outcomes, at least as far as the WTO is concerned. That
is, in a WTO dispute resolution procedure, many different
approaches and outcomes will be acceptable to the WTO, if they
follow in good faith the procedural safeguards.
- While the purely administrative process is one option,
countries could also have a mixed system where the appeals are
handled by a federal court. If judicial appeals are permitted,
the statute could set out the basis for an appeal, and could be
very specific with regard to the standards used to overturn an
administrative decision. For example, the statute could make it
very difficult to overturn an administrative decisions, or it
could make it easier for either the patent owner or the person
seeking the license to prevail on an appeal. This is one of many
areas where policy makers have discretion and choices to make. A
decision to permit a judicial appeal does not need to include the
right of the patent owner to obtain injunctive relief. For
example, in the US system for public use, nearly any government
employee can authorize use, which is not considered an
infringement of the patent, and the patent owner does not get the
right to obtain an injunction against either the government or
third parties authorized by the government. The patent holder
does, however, have a right to compensation, and the decisions
regarding compensation, including appeals, are make by federal
courts.
-
Government use.
- There is a high variance in national provisions for
government or public use of patents. Some are quite permissive,
while others are not. These are some examples of countries with
fairly liberal public use provisions in national patent laws.
- The US has very broad rights to use patents for public
purposes. As noted above, the government can use patents for any
government purpose, is not obligated to negotiate for licenses,
and does not authorize any injunctive relief to the patent owner.
The patent owner is granted compensation, as a government taking
under eminent domain laws.
- Italy gives the government the right to expropriate patents
for "Military or public interest" uses.
- In Australia, "Exploitation by the Crown" of a patent,
including use "by a person authorized in writing by the
Commonwealth or a State," is "not an infringement" of a patent.
- In Germany, "a patent shall have no effect where the Federal
Government orders that the invention be exploited in the interest
of public welfare."
- The Malaysian patent law has a special provisions for
"Rights of Government," which authorizes "the Government of the
Federation or of any State, a Ministry or Government department
or any person authorized by such Government, Ministry or
Government department" to "make use and exercise any invention,"
subject to the payment of "reasonable compensation." Like many
other countries, in Malaysia, government authorized uses of
patents are not considered an infringement.
- In Singapore, the patent law has a provision for "Use of
Patented Inventions for Services of Government," which permits
the "a Government department or a person authorized by a
Government department" to "make, use, exercise and vend the
patented invention for any purpose which appears to the
Government department necessary or expedient" for several stated
purposes, including "public non-commercial use."
- The New Zealand patent law has a provision for "Use of
patented inventions for services of the Crown," which states,
"notwithstanding any other provision of this Act, any Government
Department, and any person authorized in writing by a Government
Department, may make, use, exercise, and vend any patented
invention for the services of the Crown and anything done by
virtue of this subsection shall not amount to an infringement of
the patent." Interestingly, the only limitation on the sale of a
good to the public under this provision concerns integrated
circuits.
- In the Philippines, the relevant provision is "Use of
Invention by Government," which says, a "Government agency or
third person authorized by the Government may exploit the
invention even without agreement of the patent owner where:
(a) The public interest, in particular,
national security, nutrition, health or the
development of other sectors, as determined
by the appropriate agency of the government,
so requires; or
(b) A judicial or administrative body has
determined that the manner of exploitation,
by the owner of the patent or his licensee,
is anti-competitive. "
Like other countries, this is a separate section
in the national law from the sections on
compulsory licensing.
- The Irish patent law has provisions for "Use of Inventions
for the service of the State," which authorizes a government
Minister "to use the invention for any purpose which appears to
such Minister to be necessary or expedient-
for the maintenance of supplies and services essential to
the life of the community;
for securing a sufficiency of supplies and services
essential to the well-being of the community;
for promoting the productivity of commerce and industry,
including agriculture;
generally for ensuring that the whole resources of the
community are available for use and are used, in a manner
best calculated to serve the interests of the community;
for assisting the relief of suffering and the restoration
and distribution of essential supplies and services in
any country or territory other than the State that is in
grave distress; or
for ensuring the public safety and the preservation of
the State."
- The Switzerland patent law provides for "Expropriation of
the Patent," and states, "If public interest so requires, the
Federal Council may wholly or partially expropriate the patent."
- The UK law provides for "'Use of patented inventions for
services of the Crown," and the government's powers are quite
broad. It provides that:
"Notwithstanding anything in this Act, any government
department and any person authorised in writing by a
government department may, for the services of the Crown
and in accordance with this section, do any of the
following acts in the United Kingdom in relation to a
patented invention without the consent of the proprietor
of the patent, that is to say-
(a) where the invention is a product, may-
(i) make, use, import or keep the product, or
sell or offer to sell it where to do so would
be incidental or ancillary to making, using,
importing or
(ii) in any event, sell or offer to sell it for
foreign defence purposes or for the production
or supply of specified drugs and medicines, or
dispose or offer to dispose of it (otherwise
than by selling it) for any purpose whatever;
1. where the invention is a process, may use
it or do in relation to any product obtained
directly by means of the process anything
mentioned in paragraph (a) above;
(c) without prejudice to the foregoing, where
the invention or any product obtained directly
by means of the invention is a specified drug
or medicine, may sell or offer to sell the drug
or medicine;
(d) may supply or offer to supply to any person
any of the means, relating to an essential
element of the invention, for putting the
invention into effect;
(e) may dispose or offer to dispose of anything
which was made, used, imported or kept in the
exercise of the powers conferred by this
section and which is no longer required for the
purpose for which it was made, used, imported
or kept (as the case may be), and anything done
by virtue of this subsection shall not amount
to an infringement of the patent concerned.
-
Setting Compensation.
- Use of a patent under Article 31 of the TRIPS requires that
the patent owner is compensated. The general rule is in 31.h.
(h) the right holder shall be paid adequate
remuneration in the circumstances of each
case, taking into account the economic value
of the authorization;
In many respects, this is the most fundamental
obligation in Article 31. It is clear that
countries have considerable discretion in setting
compensation. Article 1 of the TRIPS says that
countries
"shall be free to determine the appropriate
method of implementing the provisions of this
Agreement within their own legal system and
practice."
There are of course limits to what would satisfy
this requirement, but there is already a rich
diversity of national approaches in terms of
compensation in compulsory licensing and
government use, and the WTO would be hard pressed
to justify intrusive reviews of this. Like most
Article 31 issues, the most important issue is to
provide a fair process for reaching a reasonable
result. There is no question about the power of
states to rein-in IP rights in order to assure
affordability and access, but in the process of
doing so, governments are advised to provide an
administrative record which explains the basis for
policy and specific outcomes. This doesn't have
to be complex or involve endless proceedings. It
can be simple and quick.
- The easiest way to proceed is to create set of compensation
guidelines, based upon reasonable royalties in most cases, that
will provide a framework for decision making, and also provide
some predictability and transparency for the system. These
guidelines can be administrative, or even set out in statute. In
practice, a straightforward royalty guidelines system will
facilitate early action. Government officials can simply pick
the royalty rate from the guidelines that provides a rough match
with the specific facts, and the products can be put on the
market without delay. Patent owners or generic producers could
appeal initial decisions, but the appeal process should not slow
down the introduction of generic competitors.
- One issue that should also be addressed concerns cases of
complex rights on the same product, a situation that is likely to
become more commonplace. One solution is to have the government
set a reasonable royalty that would compensate all of the various
patent owners, and have the money paid into an escrow account.
The patents owners could the work out their differences, possibly
with arbitration, and split the escrow funds when there
international differences are resolved. Again, this would permit
rapid introduction of the generic products, without waiting for
the distributional issues to be resolved among competition patent
owners.
- Japan, Germany, the Philippines and other groups have
adopted various forms of royalty guidelines, and countries can
invent their own models for this as well. PhRMA, the US based
big Pharma trade group, presented data to the USTR in February
2000 that 5 percent was the average US royalty rate for
pharmaceutical drugs, and Japan has used rates from 2 to 4
percent in the past for some purposes, while for pharmaceuticals
Germany has used 2 to 10 percent. In the Canadian case, which
according to the WHO is the most extensive use of compulsory
licensing for pharmaceutical products, the government typically
ordered royalties around 4 percent. Whatever the rate it should
be manageable, and there is no reason for the WTO to demand the
poor countries of the world to pay top dollar on medicines while
millions are dying for lack of access to treatment. Indeed, the
target royalty payment could be an approximation of the average
or median royalty paid on pharmaceutical products, for which
there exists reasonable competition among therapeutic
substitutes, and some other methodology which does not impose
high royalties from blockbuster drugs as a norm for the
developing country poor.
- In a recent presentation to the Indian domestic competitive
industry in a meeting in Mumbai, the following royalty guidelines
were recommended for developing countries:
Innovative products 3 to 5 percent
Production with modest
Innovation 2 to 3 percent
Minor patents 1 percent or less
There could be different numbers, a study to choose the
rates, or additional compensation, such as an extra royalty
payment of 1 to 2 percent over the guidelines for
productions that are particularly useful from a therapeutic
point of view, unusually expensive to develop (based upon
real evidence of costs), that reach limited audiences, or
that have other special considerations. There could also be
lowering of payments when R&D was supported by public sector
organizations, including tax based subsidies, such as the US
orphan drug tax credit program.
- In the best of all possible worlds there could be much more
analysis, such as the thoughtful pharmo-economic analysis
conducted by the Australian government to determine reimbursement
for pharmaceutical drugs. However, this is expensive in terms of
money and time of training of staff, and not only may be hard to
justify in terms of resources, but it may also make the program
harder to understand and manage.
- One important innovation in this area is to place specific
requirements that parties who seek royalties provide basic data
to governments and for the public. For example, no company
should be permitted to make entirely un-supported claims
regarding the costs of developing products, in order to plead for
higher royalty payments. If a firm wants to argue that it has
under taken large investments and risk, as of course it may have
done so, the firm should be required to provide evidence to back
up the claim. For example, the firm should disclose the actual
costs invested in the development of the product, using a
standardized disclosure format, so the data would contribute to
deeper public sector and citizen understanding of the actual
investments in products and the economics of new drug
development. This should be accompanied by data on the actual
sales of that product, since its introduction, to provide more
information on the returns from the company investments. No
appeal of a royalty rate should be permitted without such
disclosures, and indeed, countries could and I would hope would
require such disclosures before granting any compensation at all.
Such disclosures are addressed now in the Trans Atlantic Consumer
Dialogue's recent recommendations to the US and the EU on
transparency in pharmaceutical economics.10
-
Discrimination by field of technology.
- A troublesome area of the TRIPS concerns Article 27.1, which
reads in part:
. . . patents shall be available and patent
rights enjoyable without discrimination as to
the place of invention, the field of
technology and whether products are imported
or locally produced.
The meaning of this text isn't clear, because the phrase,
"field of technology" is not a well established legal term.
The big pharma companies cited this Article of the TRIPS in
their complaint against the South African Medicines Act.11
2.4. it is discriminatory in respect of the
enjoyment of patent rights in the
pharmaceutical field which discrimination is
in conflict with the provisions of Article 27
of the Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights Agreement [hereinafter
referred to as the "TRIPS Agreement"], an
international agreement binding the Republic
and to which Parliament has given effect by
the promulgation of the Intellectual Property
Laws Amendment Act, No. 38 of 1997, and
consequently such provision is in conflict
with Section 44(4) of the Constitution read
with Sections 231(2) and 231(3) of the
Constitution.
- The issue of the Article 27.1 discrimination language was
raised in WT/DS114/R, a recent WTO dispute involving Canadian
patent exceptions for research and testing on generic drugs used
for drug registration (the so called "bolar" exception) and a
Canadian patent exception that permitted stockpiling of
production in anticipation of the patent expiration. The EU
submission to the WTO stated:12
Article 27.1 of the TRIPS Agreement
(b) That Canada, by treating patent holders
in the field of pharmaceutical inventions by
virtue of these provisions less favourably
than inventions in all other fields of
technology, violated its obligations under
Article 27.1 of the TRIPS Agreement requiring
patents to be available and patent rights
enjoyable without discrimination as to the
field of technology.
The WTO considered very technical arguments over whether or
not its patent exceptions violated Article 27.1. Canada
referred to Article 32(b) of the Vienna Convention on the
Law of Treaties, which said the interpretation of treaty
terms "should not produce manifestly absurd or unreasonable
results." As summarized by the WTO panel, Canada argued:
The adoption of the meaning of Article 27.1
reflected under (a) above would clearly
violate that rule of construction. It would
lead to a requirement for "across-the-board"
derogations from patent rights, thus
compelling exceptions where there was no
practical need and reducing patent protection
more than was required in all areas save
those in which a balancing measure was
actually required. Such an incongruous
result would not be consistent with the
objectives of the TRIPS Agreement Article
27.1 that was consistent with the intent of
Article 30, i.e. allowing exceptions that
were "limited" because they were not spread
across all sectors of technology, and which
respected the objective, as reflected in the
TRIPS Agreement, of ensuring balance, by
avoiding an anti-discrimination rule which
would overwhelm other important societal
interests if it had to be applied "across the
board", without regard for particular
circumstances.
- The European Communities and their
member States did not seek to read Article
27.1 in its context and in light of the TRIPS
objectives but, instead, asserted that
Article 27.1 was absolute in nature, such
that "violations" of its provisions could not
be justified under Article 30. This
approach, in failing to give effect to the
applicable rules of interpretation, simply
led to the undesirable and absurd results
referred to above. It deprived Members of
the ability to create appropriate solutions
for specific problems on a case-by-case (or
product group by product group) basis, and
instead obliged them to impose universally
applicable measures which could be entirely
inappropriate in most contexts. It required
"limited exceptions" to be unlimited.
. . . A reference to the drafting history of
Article 27.1 was instructive. Its structure
and wording reflected two separate
negotiating thrusts: (a) a desire to ensure
that subject to certain listed exceptions,
patents would be available for inventions in
all fields of technology 13; and (b) a desire
to eliminate compulsory licence provisions
respecting food and drug products in national
patent laws. 14
. . . There was nothing in the drafting
history to suggest that the prohibition
against discrimination on the basis of field
of technology was ever meant to override
limited exceptions.
- The WTO decision in the case was more than 110 thousand
words, and explores a number of key issues in interpreting the
TRIPS. There are extensive discussions of TRIPS Article 7, 8,
27, 28, 30 and 31, plus substantive discussions of the
pharmaceutical market. The decisions includes language that
declares on the reasons for Article 27.1 was to prevent countries
from enacting compulsory licensing laws that dealt specifically
with pharmaceuticals. There is also text such as this concerning
access to generic drugs:
(b) The Global Need for Access to Essential
Medicines
- Although not manufactured in all
countries of the world, generic medicines of
course had a role to play in promoting public
health in all countries. According to the
World Health Organization, more than one
third of the world's population lacked
regular access to essential drugs. Every
year, millions of children and adults in
developing countries around the world still
died from diseases that could be readily
treated by drug therapies, and more
economically treated with generic drugs. 15
- Many countries still lacked the
facilities and expertise needed to review the
safety, efficacy and quality of drugs
destined for their national markets, and
remained dependent on reliable foreign
authorities to set the necessary standards
and on foreign generic companies to do the
necessary testing to those standards. For
example, a 1993 study of 36 African countries
conducted by the World Health Organization
had found that only three had a "limited drug
regulatory capacity". Not one African nation
had what the WHO called a "comprehensive drug
regulatory capacity".16
- A refusal to allow testing of
generic medicines for the purposes of foreign
regulatory submissions during the term of
patent protection, while permitting it for
domestic submissions, would needlessly delay
the regulatory review process in many
countries. As a result, generic drugs would
not be readily available, and many treatable
diseases would remain untreated, in the
period following patent expiry. Moreover,
such a refusal would require that tests be
repeated in their entirety in foreign
countries. The World Health Organization
opposed multiple human testing because of its
resource implications for developing
countries.17
- Consequently, if permissible "pre-
expiration testing" were to be confined to
activities related to domestic regulatory
review only, the protection of public health
would unquestionably suffer. An important
value expressly recognized in Article 8.1 of
the TRIPS Agreement would be impaired.
- In the End, the March 17, 2000 WTO panel report held that
the Canadian "bolar" provisions were not violations of Article
27.1 of the TRIPS. This decision seemed to be based largely on
the fact that the legislation itself did not specifically limit
itself to the pharmaceutical industry, even though it was clear
that this was the primary area where the legislation was having
an effect.
In sum, the Panel found that the evidence in
record before it did not raise a plausible
claim of discrimination under Article 27.1 of
the TRIPS Agreement. It was not proved that
the legal scope of Section 55.2(1) was
limited to pharmaceutical products, as would
normally be required to raise a claim of de
jure discrimination. Likewise, it was not
proved that the adverse effects of
Section 55.2(1) were limited to the
pharmaceutical industry, or that the
objective indications of purpose demonstrated
a purpose to impose disadvantages on
pharmaceutical patents in particular, as is
often required to raise a claim of de facto
discrimination. Having found that the record
did not raise any of these basic elements of
a discrimination claim, the Panel was able to
find that Section 55.2(1) is not inconsistent
with Canada's obligations under Article 27.1
of the TRIPS Agreement. Because the record
did not present issues requiring any more
precise interpretation of the term
"discrimination" in Article 27.1, none was
made. 18
- In general, the issue of permitted discrimination by sector
of the economy seems to be an important unanswered question, even
after the WTO's decision in WT/DS114/R, and poses perhaps the
most difficult issue for drafting legislation. All of the
contractions and tension so the Canadian bolar case will likely
be revisited in the future. For this reason, reports by UN
agencies, including the WHO, UNAIDS, UNCTAD or UNDP would be
useful and timely. The issues presented by this border on the
absurd, as countries will find it extremely difficult to write
laws to address in specific and limited ways important social
concerns. The United States compulsory licensing laws for clean
air and civilian nuclear energy are faced with the same issues.
The current thinking is for countries to adopt laws that provide
for compulsory licensing in broad areas like "health," and make
the argument that health isn't a field of technology. But at a
certain level it becomes ridiculous to argue that countries
cannot fashion law's that have the express mission to expand
access to medicines.
Footnotes
1
Thanks to Robert Weissman for comments on this first draft, to
Thirukumaran Balasubramaniam for research on foreign patent laws,
and to participants at several seminars, including the November
2000 UNDP meeting for HR2001 consultants, the November 28, 2000
Geneva UNCTAD Workshop on Trade in Pharmaceuticals and Human
Rights, a December 6, 2000 Bangladesh seminar organized by MSF
for the People's Health Assembly, and a December 12, meeting of
the India Drug Manufacturers Association in Mumbia, India.
2. This is only one of many important areas in patent law. For a
discussion of this and other issues, with models for state
action, see Carlos Correa, Integrating Public Health Concerns
Into Patent Legislation In Developing Countries, Geneva, October
2000, South Centre.
3 In several US cases, compensation has been based upon "what the
owner has lost, not what the taker has gained." (Leesona, 599
F.2d at 969), rejecting the argument, by patent owners, that they
are entitled to lost profits based upon sales at prevailing
commercial market rates.
4 26 AIPLA Quarterly Journal 185 (1998)
5 One example of the problems from under resourced patent
examination involved ddI, a drug for HIV/AIDS. Bristol-Myers
Squibb was able to obtain patents for formulation claims in
Thailand that were rejected by the US Patent and Trademark
Office. BMS used this patent to block generic production ddI
pills in Thailand, even though BMS was not the inventor of ddI,
and did not own a patent on the use of ddI for treating HIV/AIDS.
6 Burroughs Wellcome Co. v. Barr Lab., 828 F. Supp. 1208, 1209
(E.D.N.C. 1993).
7
http://www.bu.edu/law/scitech/volume6/Panel2.htm
8 Footnote 17 in the text is: [17] See Josh Lerner, The
Importance of Trade Secrecy: Evidence from Civil Litigation,
paper presented to the Conference on the Economics of
Intellectual Property Rights, ICARE
Institute, University of Venice, Italy (October 6-8, 1994).
9 Footnote 18 reads: [18] See JEAN O. LANJOUW & MARK SCHANKERMAN,
STYLIZED FACTS OF PATENT LITIGATION: VALUE, SCOPE AND OWNERSHIP 3
(National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 6297,
1997) (noting that crowded fields and new fields of technology
generate more patent litigation); JEAN O. LANJOUW & JOSH LERNER,
THE ENFORCEMENT OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: A SURVEY OF THE
EMPIRICAL LITERATURE 13 (National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 6292, 1997) (correlating number of times that a
patent is cited in future applications to the value of the patent
and noting that innovative technology patents are cited with
increased frequency).
10 TACD, Doc Health 6-00.
11 High Court of South Africa, Case number: 4183/98, the
Pharmaceutical Manufacturers' Association of South Africa, et
all, v. the President of the Republic of South Africa, the
Honourable Mr. N.R. Mandela N.O., et all.
12 From the WTO decision:
"The European Communities and their member States argued that, by
treating patent holders in the field of pharmaceutical inventions
less favourably than inventions in all other fields of
technology, Canada infringed its obligations contained in Article
27.1 of the TRIPS Agreement.12 The following points were advanced
in support of this argument:
- The Canadian patent legislation, which under Section
55.2(2) and 55.2(3) together with the Manufacturing and
Storage of Patented Medicines Regulations practically
speaking provided only for a 19½-year term of patent
protection, applied exclusively to product and process
patents for inventions in the field of pharmaceutical
products. During the legislative process, other fields of
technology were not even considered and no draft legislation
to extend the scope of these provisions to other or all
fields of technology was, according to the information
available to the European Communities and their Member
States, presently pending in the Canadian legislature. In
this context, it was also noteworthy that Section 55.2(2) of
the Canadian Patent Act was, taken in isolation, an
inoperative provision and created only legal effects through
the promulgation of the Manufacturing and Storage of
Patented Medicines Regulations. This Regulation was
expressly limited to "patented medicines" and could not
apply to any other product.
- Thus, the Canadian legislation discriminated against
pharmaceutical inventions by treating them less favourably
than inventions in all other fields of technology and
therefore Canada violated its obligations under Article 27.1
of the TRIPS Agreement.
13 Reference was made to the TRIPS 10+10 meeting, 16 December
1991, Speaking Note for the Chairman (unpublished).
14 Op Cit, at p. 8
15 The Worldwide Role of Generic Pharmaceuticals,
Presentation to International Generic Pharmaceuticals Association
by Dr. Jonathon D. Quick, Director of Essential Drugs and Other
Medicines, World Health Organization, June 1999. The diseases
and death rates are: respiratory infections (4 million);
diarrhoeal disease (3 million); tuberculosis (2 million);
measles (1 million); malaria (1 million); tetanus (½ million);
heart attack and strokes (5 ½ million); and cancer (3½ million).
16 Status of Drug Regulation and Drug Quality Assurance in
WHO African Region and Selected Countries, World Health
Organization, March 1999.
17 Developing International Standards for the Generic
Pharmaceutical Industry, Presentation to International Generic
Pharmaceuticals Association by Dr. Juhana E. Idanpaan-Heikkila,
Special Advisor, Quality Assurance and Safety, World Health
Organization, June 1999.
18 On the record before the Panel, there was no occasion to
consider the question raised by certain third parties -- whether
measures that are limited to a particular area of technology - de
jure or de facto - are necessarily "discriminatory" by virtue of
that fact alone, or whether under certain circumstances they may
be justified as special measures needed to restore equality of
treatment to the area of technology in question. The Panel's
decision regarding Section 55.2(1) did not touch upon that issue.
Consumer Project on Technology
P.O. Box 19367, Washington, DC 20036
http://www.cptech.org
love@cptech.org
1.202.387.8030 fax 1.202.234.5176